Tag: Start-up loss

Argentina vs Dart Sudamericana S.A., March 2023, Tax Court, Case No 35.050 I (IF-2023-35329672-APN-VOCII#TFN)

Dart Sudamericana S.A. (now Dart Sudamericana SRL) imported so-called EPS T601 pellets from related party abroad for use in its manufacturing activities. The controlled transactions had been priced using the CUP method. Following an audit the tax authorities made a transfer pricing adjustment where it had applied the transactional net margin method (TNMM). According to the tax authorities, the price paid for the pellets in the controlled transaction was higher than the arm’s length price. The adjustment resulted in an assessment of additional taxable income. Not satisfied with the assessment Dart Sudamericana filed a complaint. Tax Court Ruling The court upheld the assessment issued by the tax authorities and dismissed Dart Sudamericana’s appeal. Excerpts “In short, the appellant merely tried to prove the similarity of the product in order to carry out the price comparison, which is not sufficient for a proper study of the comparability of the transactions. At the risk of being reiterative, the transactions should be analysed, not only the products being traded. Therefore, the tax authority is right – as stated above – in its challenge to the application of the Comparable Price Method between Independent Parties – CUP or Uncontrolled Price – as a method of price analysis for the importation of EPS pellets and the application – entirely in accordance with the position taken by the appellant in the 2003 period – of the Transactional Net Margin Method for the 2004 tax period. “ “…In this regard, and as the Tax Court rightly pointed out, the OECD Committee on Fiscal Affairs has stated in its report that multi-year data are useful for providing information about the relevant business cycles and product life cycles of comparables. Differences in the business cycle or product cycle may have a substantial effect on transfer pricing conditions that must be assessed to determine comparability. Accordingly, in order to gain a full understanding of the facts and circumstances surrounding a controlled transaction, it may be useful to examine data for both the year under review and prior years. This type of analysis may be particularly useful when using one of the profit-based methods, as is the case here. The facts and circumstances of the particular case will determine whether differences in economic circumstances significantly influence the price, and whether reasonably accurate adjustments can be made to eliminate the effects of such differences” (Vid. CNACAF, Sala I, “Volkswagen Argentina S.A.”, 26/12/2019. The emphasis is my own). In this context, it is noted first of all that it is not clear from the appeals made, both in administrative proceedings and before this Court, that the use of multi-annual data was due to differences in the economic cycle of the industry under test. Likewise, it has not been proven that the economic situation the country went through in 2001 and 2002 existed in the countries of the companies used for the comparability study. The experts say nothing in their reports on the issue, limiting themselves to stating that national legislation does not prevent the use of multi-annual data, which – as mentioned above – is not in dispute. Therefore, and considering that the inclusion of data from 2001 and 2002 would inevitably increase the differences in comparability with companies abroad, I consider that the tax authority is right.” Click here for English Translation Click here for other translation ...

Italy vs SKECHERS USA ITALIA SRL, January 2022, Supreme Court, Case No 02908/2022

Skechers USA ITALIA SRL – a company operating in the sector of the marketing of footwear and accessories – challenged a notice of assessment, relating to FY 2004, by which, at the outcome of a tax audit, its business income was adjusted as a result of the ascertained inconsistency of the transfer prices relating to purchases of goods from the parent company (and sole shareholder) resident in Switzerland. The tax authorities had contested the uneconomic nature of the taxpayer company’s operations, given the losses recognised in various financial years, attributing the uneconomic nature to the artificial manipulation of the transfer prices of the purchases of goods and recalculating, consequently, the negative income component constituted by the aforesaid costs pursuant to Article 110, paragraph 7 of the TUIR, with the consequent non-deductibility of the same to the extent exceeding the normal value of the price of the goods in question. Skechers held that the losses did not derive from the costs of the intra-group purchases of the goods, but from the fixed start-up costs, not compensated by an adequate volume of sales, as an effect also of the competitive Italien market. The provincial and later the regional Tax Commission rejected the taxpayer’s appeal. The judge of appeal held that Skechers had not proved that the losses stemmed from the fixed start-up costs, which – moreover – were found only in relation to the Italien company and not in relation to the distribution companies located in other European countries; it then held that it was Skechers’ burden to prove the arm’s length nature of the costs. Skechers then filed an appeal with the Supreme Court. Judgement of the Supreme Court The Supreme Court set aside the decision and remanded the case to the Regional Tax Commission in a different composition. Excerpts “6. The following principle of law should therefore be stated: “on the subject of the determination of business income, the transfer pricing rules set forth in Article 110, paragraph 7, Presidential Decree no. 917 of 22 December 1986. 917 of 22 December 1986 imposes on the tax authorities the burden of proving the existence of transactions between related companies at a price other than the market price, using in this regard the transfer pricing methods described in the OECD Guidelines as soft law rules; once that burden of proof has been discharged, the taxpayer bears the burden of proving that those transactions took place for market values to be considered normal, having regard to the same stage of marketing, time and place where the goods and services were acquired or rendered, having regard – in particular – to the market context in which the taxpayer was operating”. 7. The judgment under appeal, in so far as it burdened the taxpayer company with the proof of the existence and inherent nature of the fixed operating costs, did not comply with the aforesaid principles, both in so far as the burden of proof lies with the Office, and in so far as the burden of proof must relate to the appropriateness of the transfer prices of the purchases of goods, in the market conditions in which the taxpayer company was required to operate, according to one of the criteria indicated in the OECD Guidelines. Nor can the burden of proof be discharged by alleging the mere uneconomicity of management (even if ascribed to the incidence of the aforesaid purchases), since the judge of the merits must verify the use of one of the methods indicated in the aforesaid Guidelines. The merit judge’s assessment must then be carried out in relation to the context in which the taxpayer company was operating at the time of the assessment, during which there had been a high incidence on the typical management of fixed operating costs, due to the start-up phase, which would have required the realisation of higher sales volumes in order to reach the break-even point. 8. The appeal must therefore be upheld and the contested judgment set aside, with reference back to the court a quo, in a different composition, also for the settlement of the costs of the proceedings.” Click here for English translation Click here for other translation ...

TPG2022 Chapter VI Annex I example 11

35. The facts in this example are the same as in Example 9, except that Company S now enters into a three-year royalty-free agreement to market and distribute the watches in the country Y market, with no option to renew. At the end of the three-year period, Company S does not enter into a new contract with Primair. 36. Assume that it is demonstrated that independent enterprises do enter into short-term distribution agreements where they incur marketing and distribution expenses, but only where they stand to earn a reward commensurate with the functions performed, the assets used, and the risks assumed within the time period of the contract. Evidence derived from comparable independent enterprises shows that they do not invest large sums of money in developing marketing and distribution infrastructure where they obtain only a short-term marketing and distribution agreement, with the attendant risk of non-renewal without compensation. The potential short-term nature of the marketing and distribution agreement is such that Company S could not, or may not be able to, benefit from the marketing and distribution expenditure it incurs at its own risk. The same factors mean that Company S’s efforts may well benefit Primair in the future. 37. The risks assumed by Company S are substantially higher than in Example 9 and Company S has not been compensated on an arm’s length basis for bearing these additional risks. In this case, Company S has undertaken market development activities and borne marketing expenditures beyond what comparable independent enterprises with similar rights incur for their own benefit, resulting in significantly lower profit margins for Company S than are made by comparable enterprises. The short term nature of the contract makes it unreasonable to expect that Company S has the opportunity of obtaining appropriate benefits under the contract within the limited term of the agreement with Primair. Under these circumstances, Company S is entitled to compensation for its at risk contribution to the value of the R trademark and trade name during the term of its arrangement with Primair. 38. Such compensation could take the form of direct compensation from Primair to Company S for the anticipated value created through the marketing expenditures and market development functions it has undertaken. Alternatively, such an adjustment could take the form of a reduction in the price paid by Company S to Primair for R watches during Years 1 through 3 ...

TPG2022 Chapter VI Annex I example 10

30. The facts in this example are the same as in Example 9, except that the market development functions undertaken by Company S in this Example 10 are far more extensive than those undertaken by Company S in Example 9. 31. Where the marketer/distributor actually bears the costs and assumes the risks of its marketing activities, the issue is the extent to which the marketer/distributor can share in the potential benefits from those activities. A thorough comparability analysis identifies several uncontrolled companies engaged in marketing and distribution functions under similar long-term marketing and distribution arrangements. Assume, however, that the level of marketing expense Company S incurred in Years 1 through 5 far exceeds that incurred by the identified comparable independent marketers and distributors. Assume further that the high level of expense incurred by Company S reflects its performance of additional or more intensive functions than those performed by the potential comparables and that Primair and Company S expect those additional functions to generate higher margins or increased sales volume for the products. Given the extent of the market development activities undertaken by Company S, it is evident that Company S has made a larger functional contribution to development of the market and the marketing intangibles and has assumed significantly greater costs and assumed greater risks than the identified potentially comparable independent enterprises (and substantially higher costs and risks than in Example 9). There is also evidence to support the conclusion that the profits realised by Company S are significantly lower than the profit margins of the identified potentially comparable independent marketers and distributors during the corresponding years of similar long-term marketing and distribution agreements. 32. As in Example 9, Company S bears the costs and associated risks of its marketing activities under a long-term contract of exclusive marketing and distribution rights for the R watches, and therefore expects to have an opportunity to benefit (or suffer a loss) from the marketing and distribution activities it undertakes. However, in this case Company S has performed functions and borne marketing expenditures beyond what independent enterprises in potentially comparable transactions with similar rights incur for their own benefit, resulting in significantly lower profit margins for Company S than are made by such enterprises. 33. Based on these facts, it is evident that by performing functions and incurring marketing expenditure substantially in excess of the levels of function and expenditure of independent marketer/distributors in comparable transactions, Company S has not been adequately compensated by the margins it earns on the resale of R watches. Under such circumstances it would be appropriate for the country Y tax administration to propose a transfer pricing adjustment based on compensating Company S for the marketing activities performed (taking account of the risks assumed and the expenditure incurred) on a basis that is consistent with what independent enterprises would have earned in comparable transactions. Depending on the facts and circumstances reflected in a detailed comparability analysis, such an adjustment could be based on: Reducing the price paid by Company S for the R brand watches purchased from Primair. Such an adjustment could be based on applying a resale price method or transactional net margin method using available data about profits made by comparable marketers and distributors with a comparable level of marketing and distribution expenditure if such comparables can be identified. An alternative approach might apply a residual profit split method that would split the relevant profits from sales of R branded watches in country Y by first giving Company S and Primair a basic return for the functions they perform and then splitting the residual profit on a basis that takes into account the relative contributions of both Company S and Primair to the generation of income and the value of the R trademark and trade name. Directly compensating Company S for the excess marketing expenditure it has incurred over and above that incurred by comparable independent enterprises including an appropriate profit element for the functions and risks reflected by those expenditures. 34. In this example, the proposed adjustment is based on Company S’s having performed functions, assumed risks, and incurred costs that contributed to the development of the marketing intangibles for which it was not adequately compensated under its arrangement with Primair. If the arrangements between Company S and Primair were such that Company S could expect to obtain an arm’s length return on its additional investment during the remaining term of the distribution agreement, a different outcome could be appropriate ...

TPG2017 Chapter VI Annex example 11

35. The facts in this example are the same as in Example 9, except that Company S now enters into a three-year royalty-free agreement to market and distribute the watches in the country Y market, with no option to renew. At the end of the three-year period, Company S does not enter into a new contract with Primair. 36. Assume that it is demonstrated that independent enterprises do enter into short-term distribution agreements where they incur marketing and distribution expenses, but only where they stand to earn a reward commensurate with the functions performed, the assets used, and the risks assumed within the time period of the contract. Evidence derived from comparable independent enterprises shows that they do not invest large sums of money in developing marketing and distribution infrastructure where they obtain only a short-term marketing and distribution agreement, with the attendant risk of non-renewal without compensation. The potential short-term nature of the marketing and distribution agreement is such that Company S could not, or may not be able to, benefit from the marketing and distribution expenditure it incurs at its own risk. The same factors mean that Company S’s efforts may well benefit Primair in the future. 37. The risks assumed by Company S are substantially higher than in Example 9 and Company S has not been compensated on an arm’s length basis for bearing these additional risks. In this case, Company S has undertaken market development activities and borne marketing expenditures beyond what comparable independent enterprises with similar rights incur for their own benefit, resulting in significantly lower profit margins for Company S than are made by comparable enterprises. The short term nature of the contract makes it unreasonable to expect that Company S has the opportunity of obtaining appropriate benefits under the contract within the limited term of the agreement with Primair. Under these circumstances, Company S is entitled to compensation for its at risk contribution to the value of the R trademark and trade name during the term of its arrangement with Primair. 38. Such compensation could take the form of direct compensation from Primair to Company S for the anticipated value created through the marketing expenditures and market development functions it has undertaken. Alternatively, such an adjustment could take the form of a reduction in the price paid by Company S to Primair for R watches during Years 1 through 3 ...

TPG2017 Chapter VI Annex example 10

30. The facts in this example are the same as in Example 9, except that the market development functions undertaken by Company S in this Example 10 are far more extensive than those undertaken by Company S in Example 9. 31. Where the marketer/distributor actually bears the costs and assumes the risks of its marketing activities, the issue is the extent to which the marketer/distributor can share in the potential benefits from those activities. A thorough comparability analysis identifies several uncontrolled companies engaged in marketing and distribution functions under similar long-term marketing and distribution arrangements. Assume, however, that the level of marketing expense Company S incurred in Years 1 through 5 far exceeds that incurred by the identified comparable independent marketers and distributors. Assume further that the high level of expense incurred by Company S reflects its performance of additional or more intensive functions than those performed by the potential comparables and that Primair and Company S expect those additional functions to generate higher margins or increased sales volume for the products. Given the extent of the market development activities undertaken by Company S, it is evident that Company S has made a larger functional contribution to development of the market and the marketing intangibles and has assumed significantly greater costs and assumed greater risks than the identified potentially comparable independent enterprises (and substantially higher costs and risks than in Example 9). There is also evidence to support the conclusion that the profits realised by Company S are significantly lower than the profit margins of the identified potentially comparable independent marketers and distributors during the corresponding years of similar long-term marketing and distribution agreements. 32. As in Example 9, Company S bears the costs and associated risks of its marketing activities under a long-term contract of exclusive marketing and distribution rights for the R watches, and therefore expects to have an opportunity to benefit (or suffer a loss) from the marketing and distribution activities it undertakes. However, in this case Company S has performed functions and borne marketing expenditures beyond what independent enterprises in potentially comparable transactions with similar rights incur for their own benefit, resulting in significantly lower profit margins for Company S than are made by such enterprises. 33. Based on these facts, it is evident that by performing functions and incurring marketing expenditure substantially in excess of the levels of function and expenditure of independent marketer/distributors in comparable transactions, Company S has not been adequately compensated by the margins it earns on the resale of R watches. Under such circumstances it would be appropriate for the country Y tax administration to propose a transfer pricing adjustment based on compensating Company S for the marketing activities performed (taking account of the risks assumed and the expenditure incurred) on a basis that is consistent with what independent enterprises would have earned in comparable transactions. Depending on the facts and circumstances reflected in a detailed comparability analysis, such an adjustment could be based on: Reducing the price paid by Company S for the R brand watches purchased from Primair. Such an adjustment could be based on applying a resale price method or transactional net margin method using available data about profits made by comparable marketers and distributors with a comparable level of marketing and distribution expenditure if such comparables can be identified. An alternative approach might apply a residual profit split method that would split the combined profits from sales of R branded watches in country Y by first giving Company S and Primair a basic return for the functions they perform and then splitting the residual profit on a basis that takes into account the relative contributions of both Company S and Primair to the generation of income and the value of the R trademark and trade name. Directly compensating Company S for the excess marketing expenditure it has incurred over and above that incurred by comparable independent enterprises including an appropriate profit element for the functions and risks reflected by those expenditures. 34. In this example, the proposed adjustment is based on Company S’s having performed functions, assumed risks, and incurred costs that contributed to the development of the marketing intangibles for which it was not adequately compensated under its arrangement with Primair. If the arrangements between Company S and Primair were such that Company S could expect to obtain an arm’s length return on its additional investment during the remaining term of the distribution agreement, a different outcome could be appropriate ...

Germany vs “Clothing Distribution Gmbh”, October 2001, BFH Urt. 17.10.2001, IR 103/00

A German GmbH distributed clothing for its Italian parent. The German tax authorities issued a tax assessment based on hidden profit distribution from the German GmbH in favor of its Italien parent as a result of excessive purchase prices, which led to high and continuous losses in Germany. The tax authorities determined the arm’s length price based on purchase prices, which the German GmbH had paid to external suppliers. However, these purchases accounted for only 5% of the turnover. The German Tax Court affirmed in substance a vGA (hidden profit distribution) as the tax authorities had provided no proff of deviation from arm’s length prices. If a hidden profit distribution is to be accepted, the profit shall be increased by the difference between the actually agreed price and the price agreed by independent contractual parties under similar circumstances – the arm’s length price. Where a range of arm’s length prices is produced, there are no legal basis for adjustment to the median value. The assessment must instead be based on the best value for the taxpayer. Distributors incurring losses for more than three years: The Senate understands its ruling in BFHE 170, 550, BStBl II 1993, 457 to say that whenever a distribution company sells products of an affiliate company and suffers significant losses for more than three years, a rebuttable presumption is triggered that the agreed transfer price has not been at arm’s length. The assumption of a rebuttable presumption means that the taxpayer can explain and prove why the actually agreed transfer price is nevertheless appropriate. This applies if the articles purchased exceeds 95% of the total turnover. The taxpayer may, For example, explain why the actual development is either due to mismanagement or other reasons that were not foreseen and, above all, that timely adaptation measures have been taken. Losses can be accepted over a period of more than three years if the corresponding proof is provided. It may be necessary to extend the period within which profit must be achieved. If proof is not provided and the taxpayer does not take any adaptive measures, a reasonable profit can be estimated and spread over the years. Click here for English translation Click here for other translation ...

Germany vs GmbH, February 1993, Bundesfinanzhof, Case No IR 3/92

The decision is about a German distribution company of international groups, which is in a continual overall loss position. This case established an important principle that: ‘… an orderly and diligent manager will, for the corporation managed by him, introduce to the market and distribute a new product only if he can expect, based on a prudent and pre-prepared economic forecast, a reasonable overall profit within a foreseeable period of time with due consideration to the predictable market development’. This decision covered the market introduction of a new product by an already established company and stated that typically a market introduction phase, losses should not be accepted for longer than three years. A later Bundesfinanzhof decision from 15 May 2002 stated that a start-up loss phase can be substantially longer than 3 years based on facts and circumstances. Click here for English translation Click here for other translation ...

TPG1979 Chapter II Paragraph 43

Another type of specially low prices which may nevertheless be claimed to be arm’s length prices may be met with where the seller’s object is market penetration. Producers may lower the prices of their goods, even to the extent of temporarily making losses, in order to enter new markets, to increase their share of an existing market, to introduce new products into the market, or to fend off increasing competition etc. One result of this may be to produce a lasting reduction in the normal market price of the relevant goods but in general specially low prices may be expected to be charged for a limited period only, with the specific object of improving the profits of the producer in the long term. Producers may not, however, be alone in this kind of activity; both producing and marketing entities may combine in such an operation, splitting the risk and sharing the profitable outcome, if any, in some way between them. Tax authorities could in principle therefore accept such low prices· charged between associated enterprises as arm’s length prices but only if independent enterprises could be expected to have fixed the prices in the same manner in comparable circumstances ...